In an economic context characterized by significant fiscal imbalances and secular stagnation in WAEMU countries, some economists advocate using money to influence real economic activity. The aim of this paper is to analyze the neutrality of money in WAEMU countries. To address this issue, we set up a 2-lag SVAR dynamic model with short-term constraints to assess the responses of output growth rate, inflation rate and real interest rate to monetary shocks. The results of our estimations show that money is weakly active in the union countries, due to the long lags between monetary policy action and its impact on output. In addition, we find that inflation rates in WAEMU countries are highly sensitive to monetary shocks, which means that the effective growth resulting from the monetary shock cannot be sustained. The transmission of these shocks on the inflation rate and output growth rate is only partial, since the pass-through coefficients of the money supply are less than unity in all countries. This study suggests that the political and economic independence of the Central Bank should be strengthened, so that monetary policy is not used for opportunistic purposes.
References
[1]
Aguir, A. (2013). L’indépendanceréelle de la banque centrale et le biaisinflationniste: Une validation empirique. Working Papers halshs-00800059.
[2]
Barro, R. J., & Gordon, D. B. (1983). Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy. National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Working Paper 1079. https://doi.org/10.3386/w1079
[3]
Bozkurt, E. (2018). The Hypothesis of Neutrality of Money: Panel Data Analysis. Journal of Yasar University, 13, 322-327.
[4]
Brandao-Marques, L., Gelos, R. G., Harjes, T., Sahay, R., & Xue, Y. (2020). Monetary Policy Transmission in Emerging Markets and Developing Economies. International Monetary Fund. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781513529738.001
[5]
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. S., & Evans, C. (2001). Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy. Working paper NBER N° 8403. https://doi.org/10.26509/frbc-wp-200107
[6]
Clément, E., & Germain, J.M. (1993). VAR et prévisions conjoncturelles. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 32, 113-135. https://doi.org/10.2307/20075928
[7]
De Grauwe, P. (1999). Économie de l’intégrationmonétaire. De Boeck Université.
[8]
Friedman, M. (1970). The Counter-Revolution in Monetary Theory, Occasional Paper 33. Institute of Economic Affairs for the Wincott Foundation.
[9]
Gbenou, K. D. A. (2021). Réexamen de l’efficacité des mécanismes de transmission de la politique monétaire dans l’UEMOA. Document d’étude et d’analyse économiques, Banque centrale des Etats de l’Afrique de l’Ouest.
[10]
Kasiwa, S. (2022). Vérification empirique de la neutralité de la monnaie en République Démocratique du Congo. GSJ, 10, 1227-1243.
[11]
Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 473-491. https://doi.org/10.1086/260580
[12]
Nakamura, E., Steinsson, J., Barro, R., & Ursúa, J. (2013). Crises and Recoveries in an Empirical Model of Consumption Disasters. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5, 35-74. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.5.3.35
[13]
Oloufade, D. K. (2015). Analysesectorielle des mécanismes de transmission de la politique monétaire dans les Etatsmembres de l’UEMOA: Une approche par l’indice de la production industrielle. Documents d’Etudes et de Recherche, N° DER14/05.
[14]
Pastén, E., Schoenle, R., & Weber, M. (2018). The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. W25303.
[15]
Rogoff, K. (1985). The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 1169-1189. https://doi.org/10.2307/1885679