It is common econometric practice to propose a system of equations, termed the “structure,” estimate each endogenous variable in the structure via a linear regression with all of the exogenous variables as arguments, and then employ one of variety of regression techniques to recapture the coefficients in the (Jacobian) arrays of the structure. A recent literature, e.g., [1], has shown that a qualitative analysis of a model’s structural and estimated reduced form arrays can provide a robust procedure for assessing if a model’s hypothesized structure has been falsified. This paper shows that the even weaker statement of the model’s structure provided by zero restrictions on the structural arrays can be falsified, independent of the proposed nonzero entries. When this takes place, multi-stage least squares, or any procedure for estimating the structural arrays with the zero restrictions imposed, will present estimates that could not possibly have generated the data upon which the estimated reduced form is based. The examples given in the paper are based upon a Monte Carlo sampling procedure.
References
[1]
Buck, A. and Lady, G. (2015) A New Approach to Model Verification, Falsification and Selection. Econometrics, 3, 466-493. http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/econometrics3030466
[2]
Samuelson, P. (1947) Foundations of Economic Analysis. Harvard University Press.
[3]
Hale, D., Lady, G., Maybee, J. and Quirk, J. (1999) Nonparametric Comparative Statics and Stability, Princeton. Princeton University Press.
[4]
Buck, A. and Lady, G. (2012) Structural Sign Patterns and Reduced Form Restrictions. Economic Modelling, 29, 462-470. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2011.12.003
[5]
Lady, G. and Buck, A. (2011) Structural Models, Information and Inherited Restrictions. Economic Modelling, 28, 2820-2831. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2011.08.021
[6]
Popper, K. (1959) The Logic of Scientific Discovery. Harper and Row. (Reprint)
[7]
Lady, G. and Maybee, J. (1983) Qualitatively Invertible Matrices. Mathematical Social Sciences, 6, 397-407. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-4896(83)90069-0
[8]
Maybee, J. (1966) New Generalizations of Jacobi Matrices. SIAM Journal of Applied Mathematics, 14, 1032-1037. http://dx.doi.org/10.1137/0114083
[9]
Klein, L. (1950) Economic Fluctuations in the U.S., 1921-1941. Cowles Commission for Research in Economics Monograph No. 11, John Wiley and Sons.
[10]
Maybee, J. and Weiner, G. (1988) From Qualitative Matrices to Quantitative Restrictions. Linear and Multilinear Algebra, 22, 229-248. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03081088808817837
[11]
Lady, G. (2000) Topics in Nonparametric Comparative Statics and Stability. International Advances in Economic Research, 5, 67-83. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/bf02295752
Lady, G. (1995) Robust Economic Models. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 19, 481-501. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-1889(94)00791-f
[14]
Goldberger, A.S. (1964) Econometric Theory. John Wiley and Sons.
[15]
Berndt, E. (1996) The Practice of Econometrics: Classic and Contemporary. Addison-Wesley Publishing Co.
[16]
System’s Science, Inc. (1985) The Oil Market Simulation Model, Documentation Report. DOE/EI/19656-2.
[17]
Energy Information Administration (1990) Oil Market Simulation User’s Manuel. DOE/EIA-M028(90), Washington DC.
[18]
Hale, D. and Lady, G. (1995) Qualitative Comparative Statics and Audits of Model Performance. Linear Algebra and Its Applications, 217, 141-154. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0024-3795(94)00125-w