全部 标题 作者
关键词 摘要

OALib Journal期刊
ISSN: 2333-9721
费用:99美元

查看量下载量

相关文章

更多...
Game Theory  2014 

Extended Games Played by Managerial Firms with Asymmetric Costs

DOI: 10.1155/2014/631097

Full-Text   Cite this paper   Add to My Lib

Abstract:

Both demand and cost asymmetries are considered in oligopoly model with managerial delegation. It shows that (i) both efficient and inefficient firms with delegation have second move advantage under quantity setting and first move advantage under price competition; (ii) the extended games under both quantity and price competition have subgame equilibria. Lastly, the social welfare of all strategy combinations is considered to find that when the efficient firm moves first and the inefficient firm moves second under price competition, the social welfare can be higher than Bertrand case, if the efficiency gap between the two firms is huge. 1. Introduction Industrial organization analysis in oligopoly and duopoly usually assumes that firms move either simultaneously or sequentially. Technically speaking, it is Cournot (Bertrand) game or Stackelberg game. In a seminal paper, Singh and Vives [1] show that, in a differentiated duopoly, Cournot competition entails higher prices and profits than Bertrand competition, whereas both firms’ output and social welfare are higher under Bertrand competition. López and Naylor [2] show that the standard result that Cournot equilibrium profits exceed those under Bertrand competition—when the differentiated duopoly game is played in imperfect substitutes—is reversible. Whether equilibrium profits are higher under Cournot or Bertrand competition is shown to depend upon the nature of the upstream agents’ preferences and on the distribution of bargaining power over the input price. Hsu and Wang [3] show that both consumer surplus and total surplus are higher under price competition than under quantity competition, regardless of whether goods are substitutes or complements. Zanchettin [4] shows that both the efficient firm’s profits and industry profits are higher under Bertrand competition when asymmetry is strong and/or products are weakly differentiated. (See Mukherjee [5] for comparison of equilibrium outcome under quantity and price competition in free entry, and in Mukherjee et al. [6], comparison of equilibrium outcome under quantity and price competition is analyzed in a vertical structure with production efficiency. The productivity difference between the downstream firms is the key to their analyses, which enriches Zanchettin [4] because in spite of the homogenous products Mukherjee et al. [6] utilize the productivity differences to justify the cost asymmetry assumed in Zanchettin [4]. Correa-López [7] also makes similar comparisons in a vertical structure but allows the downstream firm to choose either price or

References

[1]  N. Singh and X. Vives, “Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly,” The RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 15, no. 4, pp. 546–554, 1984.
[2]  M. C. López and R. A. Naylor, “The Cournot-Bertrand profit differential: a reversal result in a differentiated duopoly with wage bargaining,” European Economic Review, vol. 48, no. 3, pp. 681–696, 2004.
[3]  J. Hsu and X. H. Wang, “On welfare under Cournot and Bertrand competition in differentiated oligopolies,” Review of Industrial Organization, vol. 27, no. 2, pp. 185–191, 2005.
[4]  P. Zanchettin, “Differentiated duopoly with asymmetric costs,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, vol. 15, no. 4, pp. 999–1015, 2006.
[5]  A. Mukherjee, “Price and quantity competition under free entry,” Research in Economics, vol. 59, no. 4, pp. 335–344, 2005.
[6]  A. Mukherjee, U. Broll, and S. Mukherjee, “Bertrand versus cournot competition in a vertical structure: a note,” Manchester School, vol. 80, no. 5, pp. 545–559, 2012.
[7]  M. Correa-López, “Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly with upstream suppliers,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, vol. 16, no. 2, pp. 469–505, 2007.
[8]  J. H. Hamilton and S. M. Slutsky, “Endogeneous timing in duopoly games: stackelberg or Cournot equilibria,” Games and Economic Behavior, vol. 2, no. 1, pp. 29–46, 1990.
[9]  L. Lambertini, “Extended games played by managerial firms,” The Japanese Economic Review, vol. 51, no. 2, pp. 274–283, 2000.
[10]  L. F. S. Wang, Y.-C. Wang, and L. Zhao, “Privatization and efficiency gain in an international mixed oligopoly with asymmetric costs,” The Japanese Economic Review, vol. 60, no. 4, pp. 539–559, 2009.
[11]  Y. Nakamura and T. Inoue, “Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly: price competition with managerial delegation,” Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 30, no. 5, pp. 325–333, 2009.
[12]  J. C. Bárcena-Ruiz and M. Sedano, “Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly: weighted welfare and price competition,” The Japanese Economic Review, vol. 62, no. 4, pp. 485–503, 2011.
[13]  Y. Tomaru, Y. Nakamura, and M. Saito, “Strategic managerial delegation in a mixed duopoly with capacity choice: partial delegation or full delegation,” The Manchester School, vol. 79, no. 4, pp. 811–838, 2011.
[14]  C. Fershtman and K. Judd, “Equilibrium incentives in oligopoly,” American Economic Review, vol. 77, pp. 927–940, 1987.
[15]  S. D. Sklivas, “The strategy choice of managerial incentives,” Rand Journal of Economics, vol. 18, pp. 452–458, 1987.
[16]  J. C. Bárcena-Ruiz and M. B. Espinoza, “Long-term or short-term managerial contracts,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, vol. 5, pp. 343–359, 1996.
[17]  T. Jansen, A. van Lier, and A. van Witteloostuijn, “A note on strategic delegation: the market share case,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol. 25, no. 3, pp. 531–539, 2007.
[18]  R. A. Ritz, “Strategic incentives for market share,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol. 26, no. 2, pp. 586–597, 2008.
[19]  T. Jansen, A. V. Lier, and A. van Witteloostuijn, “On the impact of managerial bonus systems on firm profit and market competition: the cases of pure profit, sales, market share and relative profits compared,” Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 30, no. 3, pp. 141–153, 2009.
[20]  C. Manasakis, E. Mitrokostas, and E. Petrakis, “Endogenous managerial incentive contracts in a differentiated duopoly, with and without commitment,” Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 31, no. 8, pp. 531–543, 2010.
[21]  A. Chirco, M. Scrimitore, and C. Colombo, “Competition and the strategic choice of managerial incentives: the relative performance case,” Metroeconomica, vol. 62, no. 4, pp. 533–547, 2011.
[22]  J. H?ckner, “A note on price and quantity competition in differentiated oligopolies,” Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 93, no. 2, pp. 233–239, 2000.
[23]  X. H. Wang, “Price and quantity competition revisited,” Economics Bulletin, vol. 4, no. 8, pp. 1–7, 2008.
[24]  S. Mujumdar and D. Pal, “Strategic managerial incentives in a two-period Cournot duopoly,” Games and Economic Behavior, vol. 58, no. 2, pp. 338–353, 2007.
[25]  K. Basu, “Stackelberg equilibrium in oligopoly: an explanation based on managerial incentives,” Economics Letters, vol. 49, no. 4, pp. 459–464, 1995.
[26]  E. Gal-Or, “First mover and second mover advantages,” International Economic Review, vol. 26, no. 3, pp. 649–653, 1985.

Full-Text

Contact Us

service@oalib.com

QQ:3279437679

WhatsApp +8615387084133