Efforts to increase wood mobilization have highlighted the need to appraise drivers of short-run timber supply. The current study aims to shed further light on harvesting decisions of private forest owners, by investigating optimal harvesting under uncertainty, when timber revenues are invested on financial markets and uncertainty is mitigated by news releases. By distinguishing between aggregate economic risk and sector specific risks, the model studies in great detail optimal harvesting-investment decisions, with particular emphasis on the non-trivial transmission of risk on optimal harvesting, and on the way private forest owners react to news and information. The analysis of the role played by information in harvesting decisions is a novelty in forest economic theory. The presented model is highly relevant from a policy—information is a commonly used forest policy instrument—as well as a practical perspective, since the mechanism of risk transmission is at the basis of timber pricing.
References
[1]
State of Europe’s Forests 2011: Status and Trends in Sustainable Forest Management in Europe; FOREST EUROPE/FAO/UNECE, Ministerial Conference on the Protection of Forests in Europe, FOREST EUROPE Liaison Unit: Oslo, Norway, 2011. Available online: http://www.unece.org/fileadmin/DAM/timber/soef/SoEF2011_revised_version_november.pdf (accessed on 2 October 2013).
[2]
Stern, T.; Schwarzbauer, P.; Huber, W.; Weiss, G.; Aggestam, F.; Wippel, B.; Petereit, A.; Navarro, P.; Rodriguez, J.; Bostr?m, C.; de Robert, M. Identifying practices and policies for wood mobilisation from fragmented forest areas. ?kosystemdienstleistungen und Landwirtschaft. Herausforderungen und Konsequenzen für Forschung und Praxis. 22. Jahrestagung der ?sterreichischen Gesellschaft für Agrar?konomie. Universit?t für Bodenkultur: Vienna, Austria, 2012; pp. 119–120. Available online: http://oega.boku.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/Tagung/2012/OEGA_TAGUNGSBAND_2012.pdf (accessed on 2 October 2013).
[3]
Kuuluvainen, J.; Karppinen, H.; Ovaskainen, V. Landowner objectives and nonindustrial private timber supply. For. Sci. 1996, 42, 300–309.
[4]
Johansson, P.O.; L?fgren, K.G. The Economics of Forestry and Natural Resources; Basil Blackwell: Oxford, UK, 1985.
[5]
Koskela, E. Forest taxation and timber supply under price uncertainty: Perfect capital markets. For. Sci. 1989, 35, 137–159.
[6]
Koskela, E. Forest taxation and timber supply under price uncertainty: Credit rationing in capital markets. For. Sci. 1989, 35, 160–172.
[7]
Ollikainen, M. Forest taxation and the timing of private nonindustrial forest harvests under interest rate uncertainty. Can. J. For. Res. 1990, 20, 1823–1829, doi:10.1139/x90-245.
[8]
Ollikainen, M. A mean-variance approach to short-term timber selling and forest taxation under multiple sources of uncertainty. Can. J. For. Res. 1993, 23, 573–581, doi:10.1139/x93-076.
[9]
Uusivuori, J. Nonconstant Risk Attitudes and Timber Harvesting. For. Sci. 2002, 48, 459–470.
[10]
Gong, P.; L?fgren, K.G. Risk-aversion and the short-run supply of timber. For. Sci. 2003, 49, 647–656.
[11]
Caulfield, J.P. A stochastic efficiency approach for determining the economic rotation of a forest stand. For. Sci. 1998, 34, 441–457.
[12]
Taylor, R.G.; Fortson, J.C. Optimum planting density and rotation age based on financial risk and return. For. Sci. 1991, 37, 886–902.
[13]
Valsta, L.T. A scenario approach to stochastic anticipatory optimization in stand management. For. Sci. 1992, 38, 430–447.
[14]
Gong, P. Risk preferences and adaptive harvest policies for even-aged stand management. For. Sci. 1998, 44, 496–506.
[15]
We emphasize that this is a key distinctive element between [8] and [10], since the latter assumes distributional independence, while the former bases its results specifically on correlation.
[16]
Dramatiskt ras p? virkespris; Dalanytt: Falun, Sweden, 2009. Available online: http://sverigesradio.se/sida/artikel.aspx?programid=161&artikel=2683304 (accessed on 2 August 2013).
[17]
Prakash, K.; Koehler-Geib, F. The Uncertainty Channel of Contagio; IMF Working Papers 4995; The World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network, Economic Policy and Debt Department: Washington, DC, USA, 2009; p. 36.
[18]
S?drakontakt nr.4; S?drakontakt: V?xj?, Sweden, 2013. Available online: http://skog.sodra.com/Documents/Tidningar%20och%20informationsblad/S?drakontakt/2013/S?drakontakt%20nr%204%202013.pdf (accessed on 1 September 2013).
[19]
Serbruyns, I.; Luyssaert, S. Acceptance of sticks, carrots and sermons as policy instruments for directing private forest management. For. Policy Econ. 2006, 9, 285–296, doi:10.1016/j.forpol.2005.06.012.
[20]
Heikkinen, V.-P.; Kanto, A. Market model with long-term effects—Empirical evidence from Finnish forestry returns. Silva Fenn. 2000, 34, 61–69.
[21]
Heikkinen, V.-P. Co-integration of timber and financial markets—Implications for portfolio selection. For. Sci. 2002, 48, 118–128.
[22]
L?nnstedt, L.; Svensson, J. Return and risk in timberland and other investment alternatives for NIPF owners. Scand. J. For. Res. 2000, 15, 661–669, doi:10.1080/02827580050216914.
[23]
Penttinen, M.; Lausti, A. The Competitiveness and return components of NIPF ownership in Finland. The Finn. J. Bus. Econ. 2004, 2, 143–156.
[24]
Healey, T.; Corriero, T.; Rozenov, R. Timber as an institutional investment. J. Altern. Invest. 2005, 8, 60–74, doi:10.3905/jai.2005.608033.
[25]
In what follows we will use the terms “agent”, “individual” and “landowner” interchangeably, without special or technical meanings, unless otherwise stated.
[26]
The case of a signal on the forest sector will be treated in a separate section.
[27]
CARA (constant absolute risk aversion) utility is a class of utility functions u(w) characterized by the property that the associated risk aversion coefficient usually defined as ? u′′(w)/u′(w) is a constant parameter and does not vary with the wealth level.
[28]
In such an instance, final wealth would be w = p2x2 + p1x1 (1 + rf).
[29]
We refer the Reader to the next section in order to obtain additional insight on this result.
[30]
Indeed higher risk makes the signal less credible and the absolute value of the variation in the short-run timber supply induced by an increase in financial risk is higher in case of good news.
[31]
Indeed .
[32]
In the case of a negative signal, current harvesting always increases with economic risk.
[33]
Notice that we are implicitly assuming that ?γp2/?α > 0, that is σa2α2 ≤ σi2 + σs2, which is generally the case for realistic values of σa2, α, σi2, σs2.