An extensive economics literature has examined business environmental management to identify characteristics and external institutional stakeholder pressures that influence management decisions. Frequently, it is assumed that profit pursuit is the goal, and organizations subject to the same pressures respond similarly. Studies have identified a narrow set of influential stakeholders, but have revealed that organizations respond differently to them. Recent research shows that an important moderating influence is the manager’s attitude toward environmental protection, which may explain differing organizational responses, and that managers may perceive the ability to obtain utility beyond increased profit from engaging in strategic environmental management. A comprehensive framework for assessing moderating perceptions is lacking, but recent research combining institutional theory and utility maximization shows increased explanatory power and exposes the relative importance of manager perceptions. This paper synthesizes economics and management literature on institutional determinants of environmental management, utility maximization, and attitudes and behavior to illustrate the usefulness of an integrated approach for both disciplines.
References
[1]
Voluntary environmental management is defined here as “environmentally friendly actions not required by law” [2]. The term “corporate environmentalism” is not used because small businesses dominate the marketplace. Some authors argue that terms including “corporate” and the research focus on multinational corporations create an underlying expectation for greater social involvement by large companies, limiting the discourse [3,4]. The term “corporate” is used in citations where needed for consistency. Otherwise, the terms business environmental management and voluntary environmental management indicate the strategic environmental efforts of organizations of all sizes. Organizations are referred to as such, or as businesses, companies, or—for single locations—facilities.
[2]
Lyon, T.P.; Maxwell, J.W. Corporate Environmentalism and Public Policy; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2004.
[3]
Jamali, D.; Zanhour, M.; Keshishian, T. Peculiar strengths and relational attributes of SMEs in the context of CSR. J. Bus. Ethics 2009, 87, 355–377, doi:10.1007/s10551-008-9925-7.
[4]
Lepoutre, J.; Heene, A. Investigating the impact of firm size on small business social responsibility: A critical review. J. Bus. Ethics 2006, 67, 257–273, doi:10.1007/s10551-006-9183-5.
[5]
Khanna, M.; Brouhle, K. The Effectiveness of Voluntary Environmental Initiatives. In Governance for the Environment: New Perspectives; Delmas, M., Young, O., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2009; pp. 144–182.
[6]
Koehler, D.A. The effectiveness of voluntary environmental programs—a policy at a crossroads? Policy Stud. J. 2007, 35, 689–722.
[7]
González-Benito, J.; González-Benito, O. A review of determinant factors of environmental proactivity. Bus. Strat. Env. 2006, 15, 87–102.
[8]
Annandale, D.; Morrison-Saunders, A.; Bouma, G. The impact of voluntary environmental protection instruments on company environmental performance. Bus. Strat. Env. 2004, 13, 1–12.
[9]
Stoeckl, N. The private costs and benefits of environmental regulation: Which firms have the most to gain? Bus. Strat. Env. 2004, 13, 135–155.
[10]
Alberini, A.; Segerson, K. Assessing voluntary programs to improve environmental quality. Environ. Res. Econ. 2002, 22, 157–184.
[11]
Khanna, M. Non-mandatory approaches to environmental regulation: A survey. J. Econ. Surv. 2001, 15, 291–324.
[12]
Carpenter, S.R.; Arrow, K.J.; Barrett, S.; Biggs, R.; Brock, W.A.; Crépin, A.-S.; Engstr?m, G.; Folke, C.; Hughes, T.P.; Kautsky, N.; et al. General resilience to cope with extreme events. Sustainability 2012, 4, 3248–3259.
[13]
Welker, M.; Partridge, D.J.; Hardin, R. Corporate lives: New perspectives on the social life of the corporate form: An introduction to Supplement 3. Curr. Anthropol. 2011, 52, S3–S16.
[14]
Kirsch, S. Guest editorial: Sustainability and the BP oil spill. Dialect Anthropol. 2010, 34, 295–300.
[15]
Esty, D.C.; Winston, A.S. Green to Gold: How Smart Companies use Environmental Strategy to Innovate, Create Value, and Build Competitive Advantage; Yale University Press: New Haven, CT, USA, 2006.
[16]
Freeman, J.; Kolstad, C.D. Prescriptive Environmental Regulations versus Market-based Incentives. In Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation: Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience; Freeman, J., Kolstad, C.D., Eds.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2007; pp. 3–18.
[17]
Ervin, D.; Wu, J.; Khanna, M.; Jones, C.; Wirkkala, T. Motivations and barriers to corporate environmental management. Bus. Strat. Env. 2012, doi:10.1002/bse.1752. Available online: http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/bse.1752/full/ (accessed on 26 February 2013).
[18]
Khanna, M.; Koss, P.; Jones, C.; Ervin, D. Motivations for voluntary environmental management. Policy Stud. J. 2007, 35, 751–772, doi:10.1111/j.1541-0072.2007.00246.x.
[19]
Stout, L.A. The problem of corporate purpose. Issues Governance Stud. 2012, 48, 1–14.
Jones, C. Exploring new ways of assessing the effect of regulation on environmental management. J. Clean. Prod. 2010, 18, 1229–1250, doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2010.04.007.
[22]
Carpentier, C.L.; Ervin, D.E. Business Approaches to Agri-environmental Management: Incentives, Constraints and Policy Issues; Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD): Paris, France, 2002.
[23]
Reinhardt, F.L. Down to Earth: Applying Business Principles to Environmental Management; Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA, USA, 2000.
[24]
As an alternative to utility maximization, some research has combined institutional theory with a natural resource-based view of the firm. This natural resources view assumes that organizations respond to external pressures in differing ways based on their access to resources and the complementary capacities they have developed. Under this view, employee commitment may be considered a capacity, and the level may be assessed, but the motivation (e.g., altruism or deriving a monetary equivalent from certain types of utility) is not typically addressed [25,26]. This paper proposes using utility maximization to capture a more complete range of motivations. However, this is not to suggest that other approaches are not viable.
[25]
Darnall, N.; Henriques, I.; Sadorsky, P. Do environmental management systems improve business performance in an international setting? J. Int. Manag. 2008, 14, 364–376, doi:10.1016/j.intman.2007.09.006.
[26]
Hart, S. A natural-resource-based view of the firm. Acad. Manag. Rev. 1995, 20, 986–1014.
[27]
Bamberg, S.; M?ser, G. Twenty years after Hines, Hungerford, and Tomera: A new meta-analysis of psycho-social determinants of pro-environmental behavior. J. Environ. Psychol. 2007, 27, 14–25, doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2006.12.002.
[28]
Delmas, M.; Toffel, M.W. Stakeholders and environmental management practices: An institutional framework. Bus. Strat. Env. 2004, 13, 209–222, doi:10.1002/bse.409.
[29]
Sharma, S.; Ruud, A. On the path to sustainability: Integrating social dimensions into the research and practice of environmental management. Bus. Strat. Env. 2003, 12, 205–214, doi:10.1002/bse.366.
[30]
Rumelt, R.P.; Schendel, D.; Teece, D.J. Strategic management and economics. Strateg. Manag. J. 1991, 12, 5–29, doi:10.1002/smj.4250121003.
Anton, W.R.Q.; Deltas, G.; Khanna, M. Incentives for environmental self-regulation and implications for environmental performance. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2004, 48, 632–654, doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2003.06.003.
[33]
Nakamura, M.; Takahashi, T.; Vertinsky, I. Why Japanese firms choose to certify: A study of managerial responses to environmental issues. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2001, 42, 23–52, doi:10.1006/jeem.2000.1148.
[34]
Johnstone, N.; Serravalle, C.; Scapecchi, P.; Labonne, J. Public Environmental Policy and Corporate Behavior: Project Background, Overview of the Data and Summary Results. In Environmental Policy and Corporate Behavior; Johnstone, N., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc.: Northampton, MA, USA, 2007; pp. 1–33.
[35]
Montiel, I.; Husted, B.W. The adoption of voluntary environmental management programs in Mexico: First movers as institutional entrepreneurs. J. Bus. Ethics 2009, 88, 349–363, doi:10.1007/s10551-009-0282-y.
[36]
Nishitani, K. An empirical study of the initial adoption of ISO 14001 in Japanese manufacturing firms. Ecol. Econ. 2009, 68, 669–679, doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.05.023.
[37]
Frondel, M.; Horbach, J.; Renings, K. What triggers environmental management and innovation? Empirical evidence for Germany. Ecol. Econ. 2008, 66, 153–160, doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.08.016.
[38]
Khanna, M.; Anton, W.R.Q. Corporate environmental management: Regulatory and market-based pressures. Land. Econ. 2002, 78, 539–558, doi:10.2307/3146852.
[39]
Teisl, M.F.; Roe, B.; Hicks, R. Can EcoLabels tune a market? Evidence from dolphin safe labeling. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2002, 43, 339–359, doi:10.1006/jeem.2000.1186.
[40]
Dasgupta, S.; Hettige, H.; Wheeler, D. What improves environmental compliance? Evidence from Mexican industry. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2000, 39, 39–66, doi:10.1006/jeem.1999.1090.
[41]
Maxwell, J.W.; Lyon, T.P.; Hackett, S. Self-regulation and social welfare: The political economy of corporate environmentalism. J. Law Econ. 2000, 43, 583–617.
[42]
Khanna, M.; Damon, L. EPA’s voluntary 33/50 Program: Impact on toxic releases and economic performance of firms. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1999, 37, 1–25, doi:10.1006/jeem.1998.1057.
[43]
McClelland, J.D.; Horowitz, J.K. The costs of water pollution regulation in the pulp and paper industry. Land. Econ. 1999, 75, 220–232.
[44]
Henriques, I.; Sadorsky, P. The determinants of an environmentally responsive firm: An empirical approach. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1996, 30, 381–395, doi:10.1006/jeem.1996.0026.
[45]
Arora, S.; Cason, T.N. An experiment in voluntary environmental regulation: Participation in EPA’s 33/50 Program. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1995, 28, 271–287, doi:10.1006/jeem.1995.1018.
Government programs often target specific impact areas or environmental media such as the EPA-sponsored Energy Star (energy efficiency) and WasteWise (solid waste reduction and recycling) programs. Industry or trade association programs such as the chemical industry’s Responsible Care program tend to address specific issues in the target sector. International standards certification programs, such as the ISO 14000 series, seek to ensure adherence to a comprehensive environmental management strategy defined in an environmental management system (EMS) comprised of individual practices.
[48]
Videras, J.; Alberini, A. The appeal of voluntary environmental programs: Which firms participate and why? Contemp. Econ. Policy 2000, 18, 449–461, doi:10.1111/j.1465-7287.2000.tb00041.x.
[49]
Darnall, N.; Jolley, G.; Ytterhus, B. Understanding the Relationship between a Facility’S Environmental and Financial Performance. In Environmental Policy and Corporate Behavior; Johnstone, N., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc.: Northampton, MA, USA, 2007; pp. 213–259.
[50]
Yamaguchi, K. Reexamination of stock price reaction to environmental performance: A GARCH application. Ecol. Econ. 2008, 68, 345–352, doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.04.004.
[51]
Welker, M.; Wood, D. Shareholder activism and alienation: With CA comment by Robert A.G. Monks. Curr. Anthropol. 2011, 52, S57–S69, doi:10.1086/656796.
[52]
Barnea, A.; Rubin, A. Corporate social responsibility as a conflict between shareholders. J. Bus. Ethics 2010, 97, 71–86, doi:10.1007/s10551-010-0496-z.
[53]
Sharfman, M.P.; Fernando, C.S. Environmental risk management and the cost of capital. Strateg. Manag. J. 2008, 29, 569–592, doi:10.1002/smj.678.
[54]
Rondinelli, D.A.; London, T. How corporations and environmental groups cooperate: Assessing cross-sector alliances and collaborations. Acad. Manag. Exec. 2003, 17, 61–76, doi:10.5465/AME.2003.9474812.
[55]
Murdock, B.S.; Weissner, C.; Sexton, K. Stakeholder participation in voluntary environmental agreements: Analysis of 10 Project XL case studies. Sci. Technol. Hum. Val. 2005, 30, 223–250, doi:10.1177/0162243904266104.
[56]
There is no single definition for SMEs in the U.S. The Small Business Administration (SBA) sets size standards by either the volume of annual receipts or the number of employees. In this paper and literature in general, SMEs are defined as described by the European Commission (EC): companies with 250 or more employees are classified as large, those with 50–249 employees are classified as medium, those with 10–49 employees are small, and all others are micro organizations [57]. Studies comparing SBA and EC definitions revealed that the two yield comparable estimates of market proportions of large and small organizations [3].
[57]
European Commission (EC). Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs): What is an SME? Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/policies/sme/facts-figures-analysis/sme-definition/index_en.htm/ (accessed on 27 February 2013).
[58]
Reinhardt, F.L. Perspectives from the Business Literature. In Environmental Protection and the Social Responsibility of Firms: Perspectives from Law, Economics, and Business; Hay, B.L., Stavins, R.N., Vietor, R.H.K., Eds.; Resources for the Future: Washington, DC, USA, 2005; pp. 151–183.
[59]
Arora, S.; Cason, T.N. Why do firms volunteer to exceed environmental regulations: Understanding participation in EPA’s 33/50 Program. Land. Econ. 1996, 72, 413–432, doi:10.2307/3146906.
[60]
Arora, S.; Gangopadhyay, S. Toward a theoretical model of voluntary overcompliance. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 1995, 28, 289–309, doi:10.1016/0167-2681(95)00037-2.
[61]
Aerni, P. Do political attitudes affect consumer choice? Evidence from a large-scale field study with genetically modified bread in Switzerland. Sustainability 2011, 3, 1555–1572, doi:10.3390/su3091555.
[62]
Elfenbein, D.W.; McManus, B. A greater price for greater good? Evidence that consumers pay more for charity-linked products. Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy 2012, 2, 28–60, doi:10.1257/pol.2.2.28.
[63]
Baltzer, K. Customers’ willingness to pay for food quality—the case of eggs. Food Econ. 2004, 1, 78–90.
[64]
Bj?rner, T.B.; Hansen, L.G.; Russell, C.S. Environmental labeling and consumers’ choice—an empirical analysis of the effect of the Nordic Swan. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2004, 47, 411–434, doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2003.06.002.
[65]
Loureiro, M.; McCluskey, J.; Mittelhammer, R.C. Will consumers pay a premium for eco-labeled apples? J. Consum. Aff. 2002, 36, 203–219, doi:10.1111/j.1745-6606.2002.tb00430.x.
[66]
Moon, W.; Florkowski, W.J.; Brückner, B.; Schonhof, I. Willingness to pay for environmental practices: Implications for eco-labeling. Land. Econ. 2002, 78, 88–102, doi:10.2307/3146925.
[67]
Laroche, M.; Bergeron, J.; Barbaro-Forelo, G. Targeting customers who are willing to pay more for environmentally friendly products. J. Consum. Mark. 2001, 18, 503–520, doi:10.1108/EUM0000000006155.
[68]
Environmental economic literature identifies various types of “nonuse” values that may help explain willingness to pay. As literature has shown, a consumer may be willing to pay to preserve an environmental resource or feature even when they have no intention of using it. A consumer may derive satisfaction (utility) from simply knowing that a resource exists, either for its own sake or for the benefit of others. For a review of such values, refer to Crowards, 1997 [69].
[69]
Crowards, T. Nonuse values and the environment: Economic and ethical motivations. Environ. Values 1997, 6, 143–167, doi:10.3197/096327197776679167.
[70]
Wu, J.; Wirkkala, T.M. Firms’ motivations for environmental overcompliance. Rev. Law Econ. 2009, 5, 399–433.
[71]
Eichholtz, P.; Kok, N.; Quigley, J.M. Doing well by doing good? Green office buildings. Am. Econ. Rev. 2010, 100, 2492–2509, doi:10.1257/aer.100.5.2492.
[72]
Miller, N.; Pogue, D.; Gough, Q.D.; Davis, S.M. Green buildings and productivity. J. Sustain. Real. Est. 2009, 1, 65–89.
[73]
For a program to be meaningful, participants comply with requirements. If participants are not regularly audited for compliance, it is possible that some members will take advantage of free-riding opportunities [74]. For a discussion of VEP effectiveness, refer to Khanna and Broule, 2009 [5] and Koehler, 2007 [6]. For a discussion on the role of credible information in ensuring VEP effectiveness, and the expected economic effects of participation for competitive and noncompetitive firms, refer to Stoeckl, 2004 [9]. For a discussion on the role of firm cost structure in predicting the effectiveness of labeling programs, refer to Amacher, Koskela, and Ollikiainen, 2004 [75].
[74]
Rivera, J.; de Leon, P.; Koerber, C. Is greener whiter yet? The Sustainable Slopes Program after five years. Policy Stud. J. 2006, 34, 195–224, doi:10.1111/j.1541-0072.2006.00166.x.
[75]
Amacher, G.S.; Koskela, E.; Ollikainen, M. Environmental quality competition and eco-labeling. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2004, 47, 284–306, doi:10.1016/S0095-0696(03)00078-0.
[76]
De Feo, G.; de Gisi, S. Domestic separation and collection of municipal solid waste: Opinion and awareness of citizens and workers. Sustainability 2010, 2, 1297–1326, doi:10.3390/su2051297.
[77]
Valkila, N.; Saari, A. Consumer panel on the readiness of Finns to behave in a more pro-environmental manner. Sustainability 2012, 4, 1561–1579, doi:10.3390/su4071561.
[78]
Fudge, S.; Peters, M. Behaviour change in the UK climate debate: An assessment of responsibility, agency, and political dimensions. Sustainability 2011, 3, 789–808, doi:10.3390/su3060789.
[79]
Andersson, M.; Eriksson, O.; von Borgstede, C. The effects of environmental management systems on source separation in the work and home settings. Sustainability 2012, 4, 1292–1308, doi:10.3390/su4061292.
[80]
An extensive literature review revealed only two studies where greater regulatory pressures were found to be negatively associated with VEP participation [13,30]. In remaining literature, regulatory pressures have been positively associated with environmental management.
[81]
This is a result of the rulemaking process, where regulatory agencies examine the potential impacts of a specific substance and determine standards for that substance. Agencies then decide how to apply the standard across heterogeneous firms that face different compliance costs, often with input from facilities through the public comment process. Resulting standards often do not apply uniformly across all regulated facilities [82].
[82]
Magat, W.; Krupnick, A.J.; Harrington, W. Rules in the Making: A Statistical Analysis of Regulatory Agency Behavior; Resources for the Future: Washington, DC, USA, 1986.
[83]
Although “properly crafted regulation is often described as more likely to be performance based than prescriptive, as Stoeckl, 2004 [9] points out, this distinction is not necessarily valid. Theoretically at least, traditional regulation can be flexible or inflexible, depending on the nature of the policy.
[84]
Porter, M.E.; van der Linde, C. Toward a new conception of the environment-competitiveness relationship. J. Econ. Perspect. 1995, 9, 97–118, doi:10.1257/jep.9.4.97.
[85]
Maloney, M.T.; McCornick, R.E. A positive theory of environmental quality regulation. J. Law Econ. 1982, 25, 99–123.
[86]
One well-known example of strategic behavior is DuPont’s development of chlorofluorocarbon (CFCs) substitutes when research implicated CFCs in ozone layer damage. With patents on its substitutes, DuPont led industry support for the Montreal Protocol, which stipulated a 50% reduction in CFC production, gaining competitive advantage by shutting former competitors in the CFC market out of the new substitute market [15,23].
[87]
Baldwin, R.; Cave, M. Understanding Regulation: Theory, Strategy, and Practice; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1999.
[88]
Johnstone, N.; Glachant, M.; Serravalle, C.; Reidinger, N.; Scapecchi, P. Many a Slip ‘Twixt the Cup and the Lip: Direct and Indirect Public Policy Incentives to Improve Corporate Environmental Performance. In Environmental Policy and Corporate Behavior; Johnstone, N., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc.: Northampton, MA, USA, 2007; pp. 88–141.
[89]
Jones, C. What’s regulation got to do with it? Examining the impact of regulatory intensity on facility environmental management and performance. Ph.D. Thesis, Portland State University, Portland, OR, USA, 2008.
[90]
Concentration refers to distribution of production within an industry; that is, the number of businesses in the industry and the share of production each contributes. Concentrated industries are those which are dominated by a few large companies responsible for most of the output. Unconcentrated industries have fewer dominant firms and are closer to perfectly competitive.
[91]
Innes, R.; Bial, J.J. Inducing innovation in the environmental technology of oligopolistic firms. J. Ind. Econ. 2002, 50, 265–287, doi:10.1111/1467-6451.00177.
Frondel, M.; Horbach, J.; Renings, K. End-of-pipe or Cleaner Production? An Empirical Comparison of Environmental Innovation Decisions across OECD Countries. In Environmental Policy and Corporate Behavior; Johnstone, N., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc.: Northampton, MA, USA, 2007; pp. 174–212.
[94]
Simpson, M.; Taylor, N.; Barker, K. Environmental responsibility in SMEs: Does it deliver competitive advantage? Bus. Strat. Env. 2004, 13, 156–171, doi:10.1002/bse.398.
[95]
Boiral, O. Corporate greening through ISO 14001: A rational myth? Organ. Sci. 2007, 18, 127–146, doi:10.1287/orsc.1060.0224.
[96]
Jones, C. Voluntary environmental program participation in selected Oregon manufacturing, construction, accommodation, and transport sectors: Perceived influences on participation and effects on effort and outcomes. Master of Environmental Management project, Portland State University, Portland, OR, USA, 2007.
[97]
Berrone, P.; Gomez-Mejia, L.R. Environmental performance and executive compensation: An integrated agency-institutional perspective. Acad. Manag. J. 2009, 52, 103–126, doi:10.5465/AMJ.2009.36461950.
[98]
Henriques, I.; Sadorsky, P. Environmental Management Systems and Practices: An International Perspective. In Environmental Policy and Corporate Behavior; Johnstone, N., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc.: Northampton, MA, USA, 2007; pp. 34–87.
[99]
Arimura, T.; Hibiki, A.; Johnstone, N. An Empirical Study of Environmental R&D: What Encourages Facilities to be Environmentally Innovative? In Environmental Policy and Corporate Behavior; Johnstone, N., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc.: Northampton, MA, USA, 2007; pp. 142–173.
[100]
When size is measured in terms of sales or revenues, results are less consistent. Studies have found either no significant relationship between revenue level and environmental management effort, or that relationships are nonlinear, with midsize organizations exhibiting greater effort than other organizations [9,13,101,102].
[101]
Navaretti, G.B.; Vendels, A.J. Multinational Firms in the World Economy; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2004.
[102]
Stuart, A. Is going public going out of style? CFO Magazine. May 2011. Available online: http://www.cfo.com/article.cfm/14570187 (accessed on 3 February 2013).
[103]
Herremans, I.; Herschovis, M.S.; Bertels, S. The influence of competing logics on corporate environmental action. J. Bus. Ethics 2009, 89, 449–472, doi:10.1007/s10551-008-0010-z.
[104]
Gadenne, D.L.; Kennedy, J.; McKeiver, C. An empirical study of environmental awareness and practices in SMEs. J. Bus. Ethics 2009, 84, 45–63.
[105]
Masurel, E. Why SMEs invest in environmental measures: Sustainability evidence from small and medium-sized printing firms. Bus. Strat. Env. 2007, 16, 190–201, doi:10.1002/bse.478.
[106]
Regnier, E.; Tovey, C. Time horizons of environmental versus non-environmental costs: Evidence from US tort lawsuits. Bus. Strat. Env. 2007, 16, 249–265, doi:10.1002/bse.494.
[107]
Bendell, J.; Kearins, K. The political bottom line: The emerging dimension to corporate social responsibility for sustainable development. Bus. Strat. Env. 2005, 14, 372–383.
[108]
Marshall, R.S.; Cordano, M.; Silverman, M. Exploring individual and institutional drivers of proactive environmentalism in the US wine industry. Bus. Strat. Env. 2005, 14, 92–109, doi:10.1002/bse.433.
[109]
Gouldson, A.; Sullivan, R. Corporate environmentalism: Tracing the links between policies and performance using corporate reports and public registers. Bus. Strat. Env. 2007, 16, 1–11, doi:10.1002/bse.543.
[110]
World Stock Exchanges. Top ten stock exchanges in the world. Available online: http://www.world-stock-exchanges.net/top10.html (accessed on 3 February 2013).
Baron, D.P. Private politics, corporate social responsibility, and integrated strategy. J. Econ. Manag. Strat. 2001, 10, 7–45.
[113]
Conventional profit-maximizing theories also explain why different firms choose different strategies, based on the variation in marginal abatement and transactions costs across firms. Profit-maximizing firms choose the level of pollution abatement that equates their marginal costs with their marginal benefits, or implement voluntary initiatives to the extent that the marginal transactions costs are equal or less than the marginal benefits of the initiative [5,114]. Utility maximization does not refute these assumptions, but can also explain variations in strategy that are not based strictly on profit motivations.
[114]
Segerson, K.; Miceli, T.J. Voluntary environmental agreements: Good or bad news for environmental protection? J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1998, 36, 109–130, doi:10.1006/jeem.1998.1040.
[115]
Busch, T.; Hoffmann, V.T. Ecology-driven real options: An investment framework for incorporating uncertainties in the context of the natural environment. J. Bus. Ethics 2009, 90, 295–310, doi:10.1007/s10551-009-0043-y.
[116]
Simon, H.A. A behavioral model of rational choice. Q. J. Econ. 1955, 69, 99–118, doi:10.2307/1884852.
[117]
Wu, J. Environmental compliance: The good, the bad, and the super green. J. Environ. Manag. 2009, 90, 3363–3381, doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2009.05.017.
[118]
Other studies have indicated that the perception that the environment is an important issue is a determinant of a variety of proactive environmental management strategies, including: the presence of an environmental plan or EMS, third-party EMS certification, the number of environmental management practices, and participation in a VEP [18,98]. While not an attitude per se, this perception may reflect a manager’s understanding of the importance of the environment to business operations, thereby moderating other institutional influences.
[119]
Crossland, C.; Hambrick, D.C. How national systems differ in their constraints on corporate executives: A study of CEO effects in three countries. Strateg. Manag. J. 2007, 28, 767–789, doi:10.1002/smj.610.
[120]
Barker, V.L., III; Mueller, G.C. CEO characteristics and firm R&D spending. Manag. Sci. 2002, 48, 782–801, doi:10.1287/mnsc.48.6.782.187.
[121]
Johnson, L.K. Do CEOs matter? MIT Sloan Manag. Rev. 2002, 43, 8–9.
[122]
Cordano, M.; Frieze, I.H. Pollution reduction preferences of U.S. environmental managers: Applying Ajzen’s theory of planned behavior. Acad. Manag. J. 2000, 43, 627–641, doi:10.2307/1556358.
[123]
Brockner, J.; James, E.H. Toward an understanding of when executives see crisis as opportunity. J. Appl. Behav. Sci. 2008, 44, 94–115, doi:10.1177/0021886307313824.
[124]
Buysse, K.; Verbeke, A. Proactive environmental strategies: A stakeholder management perspective. Strateg. Manag. J. 2003, 24, 453–470.
[125]
Ostrom, E. Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. Am. Econ. Rev. 2010, 3, 641–672, doi:10.1257/aer.100.3.641.
[126]
Ostrom, E. Policy analysis in the future of good societies. Good Soc. 2002, 11, 42–48, doi:10.1353/gso.2002.0013.