Rather than conforming to the assumption of perfect rationality in neoclassical economic theory, decision behavior has been shown to display a host of systematic biases. Properly understood, these patterns can be instrumentalized to improve outcomes in the public realm. We conducted a laboratory experiment to study whether decisions over health insurance policies are subject to status quo bias and, if so, whether experience mitigates this framing effect. Choices in two treatment groups with status quo defaults are compared to choices in a neutrally framed control group. A two-step design features sorting of subjects into the groups, allowing us to control for selection effects due to risk preferences. The results confirm the presence of a status quo bias in consumer choices over health insurance policies. However, this effect of the default framing does not persist as subjects repeat this decision in later periods of the experiment. Our results have implications for health care policy, for example suggesting that the use of non-binding defaults in health insurance can facilitate the spread of co-insurance policies and thereby help contain health care expenditure.
References
[1]
Thaler, R.H. Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 1980, 1, 39–60, doi:10.1016/0167-2681(80)90051-7.
[2]
Samuelson, W.; Zeckhauser, R. Status quo bias in decision making. J. Risk Uncertainty 1988, 1, 7–59, doi:10.1007/BF00055564.
[3]
Tversky, A.; Kahneman, D. Rational choice and the framing of decisions. J. Bus. 1986, 59, 251–278.
[4]
Beshears, J.; Choi, J.; Laibson, D.; Madrian, B. The importance of default options for retirement saving outcomes, evidence from the United States. In Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment; Brown, I.R., Liebman, J.B., Wise, D.A., Eds.; University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2009; pp. 167–200.
[5]
Carroll, G.; Choi, J.; Laibson, D.; Madrian, B.; Metrick, A. Optimal defaults and active decisions. Q. J. Econ. 2009, 124, 1639–1674, doi:10.1162/qjec.2009.124.4.1639.
[6]
Pichert, D.; Katsikopoulos, K.V. Green defaults, information presentation and pro-environmental behavior. J. Environ. Psychol. 2008, 28, 63–73, doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004.
[7]
Paha, J.; Rompf, D.; Warnecke, C. Customer choice patterns in passenger rail competition. Transport Res. Pol. Pract. 2013, 50, 209–227, doi:10.1016/j.tra.2013.01.037.
[8]
Abadie, A.; Gay, S. The impact of presumed consent legislation on cadaveric organ donation, a cross-country study. J. Health. Econ. 2006, 25, 599–620, doi:10.1016/j.jhealeco.2006.01.003.
[9]
Boonen, L.H.H.M.; Schut, F.T.; Donkers, B.; Koolman, X. Which preferred providers are really preferred? Effectiveness of insurers’ channeling incentives on pharmacy choice. Int. J. Health Care Finance Econ. 2009, 9, 347–366, doi:10.1007/s10754-009-9055-5.
[10]
Tsutsui, Y.; Benzion, U.; Shahrabani, S. Economic and behavioral factors in an individual’s decision to take the influenza vaccination in Japan. J. Socio-Econ. 2012, 41, 594–602.
[11]
Brown, A.L.; Kagel, J.H. Behavior in a simplified stock market: The status quo bias, the disposition effect and the ostrich effect. Ann. Finance 2009, 5, 1–14, doi:10.1007/s10436-007-0092-0.
[12]
Altman, S.; Falk, A. The Impact of Cooperation Defaults on Voluntary Contributions to Public Goods; University of Bonn: Bonn, Germany, 2009.
[13]
Arrow, K.J. Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. Am. Econ. Rev. 1963, 53, 941–973.
[14]
Mossin, J. Aspects of rational insurance purchasing. J. Polit. Econ. 1968, 76, 553–568.
[15]
Zweifel, P.; Breyer, F.; Kifmann, M. Health Economics, 2nd ed.; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2009.
[16]
Manning, W.G.; Newhouse, J.P.; Duan, N.; Keeler, E.B.; Leibowitz, A. Health insurance and the demand for medical care, evidence from a randomized experiment. Am. Econ. Rev. 1987, 77, 251–277.
[17]
Felder, S.; Werblow, A. A physician fee that applies to acute but not to preventive care: Evidence from a German deductible program. Schmollers Jahrbuch 2008, 128, 191–212, doi:10.3790/schm.128.2.191.
[18]
Feldstein, M.S. The welfare loss of excess health insurance. J. Polit. Econ. 1973, 81, 251–280.
[19]
Pauly, M.V. Dumb decisions or as smart as the average politician? Economic and behavioral explanations for insurance demand. In The Irrational Economist, Making Decisions in a Dangerous World; Michel-Kerjan, E., Slovic, P., Eds.; Public Affairs: New York, NY, USA, 2010; pp. 132–141.
Kahneman, D.; Knetsch, J.L.; Thaler, R.H. Anomalies, the endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. J. Econ. Perspect. 1991, 5, 193–206.
[22]
Camerer, C.; Issacharoff, S.; Loewenstein, G.; O’Donoghue, T.; Rabin, M. Regulation for conservatives, behavioral economics and the case for “asymmetric paternalism”. Univ. Penn. Law Rev. 2003, 151, 1211–1254, doi:10.2307/3312889.
[23]
Tversky, A.; Kahneman, D. Loss aversion in riskless choice, a reference-dependent model. Quart. J. Econ. 1991, 106, 1039–1061, doi:10.2307/2937956.
[24]
Tversky, A.; Kahneman, D. Judgment under uncertainty, heuristics and biases. Science 1974, 185, 1124–1131.
[25]
Arkes, H.R.; Blumer, C. The psychology of sunk cost. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 1985, 35, 124–140, doi:10.1016/0749-5978(85)90049-4.
[26]
Loomes, G.; Sugden, R. Regret theory, an alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty. Econ. J. 1982, 92, 805–824, doi:10.2307/2232669.
[27]
Johnson, E.J.; Hershey, J.; Meszaros, J.; Kunreuther, H. Framing, probability distortions, and insurance decisions. J. Risk Uncertainty 1993, 7, 35–51, doi:10.1007/BF01065313.
[28]
Strombom, B.A.; Buchmueller, T.C.; Feldstein, P.J. Switching costs, price sensitivity and health plan choice. J. Health. Econ. 2002, 21, 89–116, doi:10.1016/S0167-6296(01)00124-2.
[29]
Frank, R.; Lamiraud, K. Choice, price competition and complexity in markets for health insurance. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2009, 71, 550–562, doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2009.04.005.
[30]
Schram, A.; Sonnemans, J. How individuals choose health insurance, an experimental analysis. Euro. Econ. Rev. 2011, 55, 799–819, doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2011.01.001.
[31]
Zweifel, P.; Leukert, K.; Berner, S. Preferences for Health Insurance in Germany and the Netherlands—A Tale of Two Countries; University of Zurich: Zurich, Switzerland, 2010.
[32]
Falk, A.; Heckman, J.J. Lab experiments are a major source of knowledge in the social sciences. Science 2009, 326, 535–538, doi:10.1126/science.1168244.
[33]
Levitt, S.D.; List, J.A. What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world? J. Econ. Perspect. 2007, 21, 153–174, doi:10.1257/jep.21.2.153.
[34]
L?fgren, A.; Martinsson, P.; Hennlock, M.; Sterner, T. Are experienced people affected by a pre-set default option—Results from a field experiment. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2012, 63, 66–72, doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2011.06.002.
[35]
Shapira, Z.; Venezia, I. On the preference for full-coverage policies. Why do people buy too much insurance? J. Econ. Psychol. 2008, 29, 747–761.
[36]
List, J.A. Does market experience eliminate market anomalies? Q. J. Econ. 2003, 118, 41–71, doi:10.1162/00335530360535144.
[37]
List, J.A. Neoclassical theory versus prospect theory, evidence from the marketplace. Econometrica 2004, 72, 615–625.
[38]
List, J.A.; Haigh, M.S. A simple test of expected utility theory using professional traders. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2005, 102, 945–948, doi:10.1073/pnas.0408022101.
[39]
Fuchs, V.R. The future of health economics. J. Health Econ. 2000, 19, 141–157, doi:10.1016/S0167-6296(99)00033-8.
[40]
Halpern, S.D.; Ubel, P.A.; Asch, D.A. Harnessing the power of default options to improve health care. N. Eng. J. Med. 2007, 375, 1340–1344, doi:10.1056/NEJMsb071595.
[41]
Liebman, J.; Zeckhauser, R. Simple humans, complex insurance, subtle subsidies. In Using Taxes to Reform Health Insurance, Pitfalls and Promises; Aaron, H.J., Burman, L.E., Eds.; Brookings Institution Press: Washington, DC, USA, 2008; pp. 230–262.
[42]
Gorter, J.; Schilp, P. Determinants of Consumer Financial Risktaking, Evidence from Deductible Choice; De Nederlandsche Bank: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2009.
[43]
Gorter, J.; Schilp, P. Risk Preferences over Small Stakes: Evidence from Deductible Choice; De Nederlandsche Bank: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2012.
Holt, C.A.; Laury, S.K. Risk aversion and incentive effects, new data without order effects. Am. Econ. Rev. 2005, 95, 902–912, doi:10.1257/0002828054201459.
[46]
Harrison, G.W.; List, J.A.; Towe, C. Naturally occurring preferences and exogenous laboratory experiments. A case study of risk aversion. Econometrica 2007, 75, 433–458, doi:10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00753.x.
[47]
Baltussen, G.; Post, T.; van den Assem, M.J.; Wakker, P.P. Random incentive systems in a dynamic choice experiment. Exp. Econ. 2012, 15, 418–443, doi:10.1007/s10683-011-9306-4.
[48]
Cubitt, R.; Starmer, C.; Sugden, R. On the validity of the random lottery incentive system. Exp. Econ. 1998, 1, 115–131.
[49]
Starmer, C.; Sugden, R. Does the random-lottery incentive system elicit true preferences? An experimental investigation. Am. Econ. Rev. 1991, 81, 971–978.
[50]
Laury, S.K. Pay One or Pay All, Random Selection of One Choice for Payment; Georgia State University: Atlanta, GA, USA, 2006.
[51]
Kahneman, D.; Tversky, A. Prospect theory. An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 1979, 47, 263–292, doi:10.2307/1914185.
[52]
Greiner, B. The Online Recruitment System ORSEE 2.0—A Guide for the Organization of Experiments in Economics; University of Cologne: Cologne, Germany, 2004.
[53]
Fischbacher, U. zTree, Zurich toolboox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp. Econ. 2007, 10, 171–178, doi:10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4.
[54]
Shampanier, K.; Mazar, N.; Ariely, D. Zero as a special price: The true value of free products. Mark. Sci. 2007, 26, 742–757, doi:10.1287/mksc.1060.0254.
[55]
Braga, J.; Humphrey, S.J.; Starmer, C. Market experience eliminates some anomalies—and creates new ones. Europ. Econ. Rev. 2009, 53, 401–416, doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2008.06.005.