全部 标题 作者
关键词 摘要

OALib Journal期刊
ISSN: 2333-9721
费用:99美元

查看量下载量

相关文章

更多...

The Effect of Labour Turnover Costs on Average Labour Demand When Recessions Are More Persistent than Booms

DOI: 10.1155/2013/138182

Full-Text   Cite this paper   Add to My Lib

Abstract:

This paper examines how labour turnover costs affect average labour demand when troughs are more persistent than booms. We show that the effect of firing costs on average labour demand is more expansionary (or less contractionary): the greater is the difference between the persistence of troughs and the persistence of booms, and the more prolonged are the macroeconomic shocks. This analysis may shed some light on the expected effect of a reduction of firing costs when an economy is suffering more prolonged recessions (relative to booms): average labour demand will be lower. 1. Introduction Politicians and journalists often attribute the high unemployment in many European countries to their stringent job security legislation, and particularly to their state-mandated firing costs. However, the theoretical literature on the long-run effects of firing costs on employment has generated mixed results (There is also no agreement in the empirical literature. See OECD [1], Layard et al. [2], Lazear [3], Bertola [4], Hopenhayn and Rogerson [5], Nickell [6], Heckman and Pages [7].). Bentolila and Bertola [8] and Bertola [9] have argued that firing costs tend to raise (rather than reduce) the average level of employment since they discourage firing more than hiring in any given firm. Other contributions show factors that pull in the opposite direction: Bentolila and Saint-Paul [10] indicate that when firms face heterogeneous productivity shocks, a rise in firing costs reduces the number of firms engaged in firing. Hopenhayn and Rogerson [5] consider that the increase in firing costs reduces the entry of firms (in an industry equilibrium with firm entry and exit) and thus labour demand falls. Díaz-Vázquez et al. [11] show that when there is on-the-job learning, an increase in firing costs may reduce average employment over the cycle. This paper and Díaz-Vázquez and Snower [12–14] also show that the wage effects of firing costs may reduce average employment (as shown in the literature, firing costs give power to insiders in the wage negotiation (see Lindbeck and Snower, [15])). Ljungqvist and Sargent [16] argue that the existence of firing costs can help explain the high European unemployment of recent decades. However, this literature has not investigated how the average employment effect of firing costs depends on the asymmetry in the persistence of macroeconomic booms and troughs (in Bentolila and Bertola [8], the shocks are permanent (namely, they are assumed to follow a random walk process), whereas in Bentolila and Saint-Paul [10] they are temporary (namely,

References

[1]  OECD, Employment Outlook 2004, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2004.
[2]  R. Layard, S. Nickell, and R. Jackman, Unemployment: Macroeconomic Performance and the Labor Market, Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK, 1991.
[3]  E. P. Lazear, “Job security provisions and employment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 105, no. 3, pp. 699–726, 1990.
[4]  G. Bertola, “Job security, employment and wages,” European Economic Review, vol. 34, no. 4, pp. 851–886, 1990.
[5]  H. A. Hopenhayn and R. Rogerson, “Job turnover and policy evaluation: a general equilibrium approach,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 101, no. 5, pp. 915–938, 1993.
[6]  S. Nickell, “Unemployment and labor market rigidities: Europe versus North America,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 11, no. 3, pp. 55–74, 1997.
[7]  J. Heckman and C. Pages, “The cost of job security regulation: evidence from Latin American labor markets,” NBER Working Paper 7773, 2000.
[8]  S. Bentolila and G. Bertola, “Firing costs and labor demand: how bad is eurosclerosis?” Review of Economic Studies, vol. 57, no. 3, pp. 381–402, 1990.
[9]  G. Bertola, “Labor turnover costs and average labor demand,” Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 10, pp. 389–411, 1992.
[10]  S. Bentolila and G. Saint-Paul, “A model of labor demand with linear adjustment costs,” Labour Economics, vol. 1, no. 3-4, pp. 303–326, 1994.
[11]  P. Díaz-Vázquez, D. J. Snower, and L. E. Arjona-Béjar, “On-the-job learning, firing costs and employment,” Contributions to Economic Analysis and Policy, vol. 4, no. 1, article 2, 2005.
[12]  P. Díaz-Vázquez and D. J. Snower, “Employment, macroeconomic fluctuations and job security,” CEPR Discussion Paper 1430, CEPR, London, UK, 1996.
[13]  P. Díaz-Vázquez and D. J. Snower, “Can insider power affect employment?” German Economic Review, vol. 4, no. 2, pp. 139–150, 2003.
[14]  P. Díaz-Vázquez and D. J. Snower, “On-the-job learning and the effects of insider power,” Labour Economics, vol. 13, no. 3, pp. 317–341, 2006.
[15]  A. Lindbeck and D. J. Snower, The Insider-Outsider Theory of Employment and Unemployment, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, USA, 1989.
[16]  L. Ljungqvist and T. J. Sargent, “Two questions about European unemployment,” Econometrica, vol. 76, no. 1, pp. 1–29, 2008.
[17]  L. Nunziata, “Labour market institutions and the cyclical dynamics of employment,” Labour Economics, vol. 10, no. 1, pp. 31–53, 2003.
[18]  Y. F. Chen, D. Snower, and G. Zoega, “Labour-market institutions and macroeconomic shocks,” Labour, vol. 17, no. 2, pp. 247–270, 2003.
[19]  M. Veracierto, “Firing costs and business cycle fluctuations,” International Economic Review, vol. 49, no. 1, pp. 1–39, 2008.
[20]  F. Zanetti, “Labor market institutions and aggregate fluctuations in a search and matching model,” European Economic Review, vol. 55, no. 5, pp. 644–658, 2011.

Full-Text

Contact Us

service@oalib.com

QQ:3279437679

WhatsApp +8615387084133