全部 标题 作者
关键词 摘要

OALib Journal期刊
ISSN: 2333-9721
费用:99美元

查看量下载量

相关文章

更多...

Optimal Educational Investment: Domestic Equity and International Competition

DOI: 10.5402/2012/909727

Full-Text   Cite this paper   Add to My Lib

Abstract:

We construct a family of models to analyse the effect on optimal educational investment of (i) society's preferences for equity and (ii) competition between countries. The models provide insights about the impact of a variety of parameters on optimal policy. In particular, we identify a form of “overeducation” that is new to the literature and provide a counterexample to a common finding in the literature on fiscal federalism. 1. Introduction Economists’ interest in education often focuses upon the rate of return to schooling investments. Yet it is a characteristic of the education system in many countries that, for the most part, schooling is funded out of the public purse. While one might imagine that governments should seek to “equalise rates of return in all directions” [1], it is often the case that the authorities have broader objectives that inform their educational investments. For example, a government may have preferences about equity as well as efficiency. Or it may, for various reasons, be concerned to ensure that its own investment in its people’s skills does not fall behind investments made by other countries. We examine these issues by developing, in the next section, a series of models that can aid our understanding of how, under a variety of conditions, the optimal provision of publicly funded education is determined. 2. The Model In this section we present a family of related models of education and the tax system in order to provide insights into how governments can reach decisions about the optimal funding of education where (i) society has preferences about equity and (ii) decisions have impacts across countries. The basic structure of the model builds on the analysis of Johnes [2]. 2.1. Equity Suppose that the disposable income of individual is given by where is a basic income to be defined more precisely later, is a binary variable that indicates whether the th individual has undertaken schooling or not, is the proportional rate of income tax, and is the income premium associated with schooling. Both and are assumed exogenous. Tax revenues are used solely for the purpose of financing education which, we assume, takes place instantaneously. This distinguishes the model from a family of models typified by that of Bovenberg and Jacobs [3], where taxation also serves a redistributive purpose. In our model we keep the tax system simple in order to facilitate the extension to the international case in Section 2.2 below. In the present model, tax revenues fund education as a means of achieving the redistribution of income, but they could

References

[1]  M. Blaug, L. Richard, and W. Maureen, “1969,” in The Causes of Graduate Unemployment in India, Penguin, Harmondsworth, UK.
[2]  G. Johnes, “The evaluation of welfare under alternative models of higher education finance,” in Markets in Higher Education: Rhetoric or Reality? P. Teixeira, B. Jongbloed, D. Dill, and A. Amaral, Eds., Kluwer, London, UK, 2004.
[3]  A. L. Bovenberg and B. Jacobs, “Redistribution and education subsidies are Siamese twins,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 89, no. 11-12, pp. 2005–2035, 2005.
[4]  D. Acemoglu and J. Angrist, “How large are human capital externalities? Evidence from compulsory schooling laws,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, B. Bernanke and K. Rogoff, Eds., pp. 9–59, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, USA, 2001.
[5]  R. B. Freeman, “Are your wages set in Beijing?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 9, no. 3, pp. 15–32, 1995.
[6]  J. F. Nash, “Non-cooperative games,” Annals of Mathematics, vol. 54, pp. 286–295, 1951.
[7]  M. C. Daly, F. Büchel, and G. J. Duncan, “Premiums and penalties for surplus and deficit education: evidence from the United States and Germany,” Economics of Education Review, vol. 19, no. 2, pp. 169–178, 2000.
[8]  P. Dolton and A. Vignoles, “The incidence and effects of overeducation in the UK graduate labour market,” Economics of Education Review, vol. 19, no. 2, pp. 179–198, 2000.
[9]  J. Edwards and M. Keen, “Tax competition and Leviathan,” European Economic Review, vol. 40, no. 1, pp. 113–134, 1996.

Full-Text

Contact Us

service@oalib.com

QQ:3279437679

WhatsApp +8615387084133