全部 标题 作者
关键词 摘要

OALib Journal期刊
ISSN: 2333-9721
费用:99美元

查看量下载量

相关文章

更多...

Rent Extraction through Alternative Forms of Competition in the Provision of Paternalistic Goods

DOI: 10.5402/2012/703541

Full-Text   Cite this paper   Add to My Lib

Abstract:

We compare the properties in terms of rent extraction of spatial competition and monopoly franchises using Dutch first price auctions, two of the most widely used tools to regulate public service provision. In a framework where the regulator can imperfectly observe costs, but the latter are not necessarily private information to each competitor, spatial competition is more effective in extracting rent if providers are very different in their productivity and if they can observe the costs of their competitors. When they are quite similar and have limited information on the competitors' characteristics, the use of a monopoly franchise through an auction mechanism should be preferred. In the latter environment, a multiple object auction allows more rent to be extracted from the provider. 1. Introduction Service provision in the public sector has experienced a substantial change through the introduction of forms of competition among providers. For essential facilities (such as energy, gas, and water), competition for and in the market, along with some forms of price regulation, is envisaged. For other local services, competition for the market and price regulation is often used.1 Production costs often become private information to the provider, a problem which the literature has long recognised [1], and for which specific solutions have been proposed [2–7]. In the recent past, policy makers have extended these reforms to the provision of health, social care, education, and other local services. Forms of competition such as spatial competition and monopoly franchises [8–13] have been implemented, but none of them has proved to be optimal. For education, the empirical evidence shows that competition does not have an impact on the cost of providing the service, but it might improve school performances [14–17]; for hospital care and nursing homes the evidence is fairly mixed [18–23]; in all these sectors cream skimming practices might arise [24]. We argue that performances depend on the specific characteristics of each service, which calls for a more accurate investigation of providers’ responses to alternative regulatory instruments in this very particular context. Services are in fact usually produced on demand (and the latter is not very elastic because they are often perceived as a primary need); they cannot be stocked or transported; and their quality is difficult to verify.2 The supply of these services is often associated with the notion of soft paternalism [25]; in other words Government thinks that individuals should use them irrespective of their

References

[1]  D. P. Baron and R. B. Myerson, “Regulating a monopolist with unknown costs,” Econometrica, vol. 50, no. 4, pp. 911–930, 1982.
[2]  E. Auriol and J. J. Laffont, “Regulation by duopoly,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, vol. 1, no. 3, pp. 507–533, 1992.
[3]  A. Bower, “Procurement policy and contracting efficiency,” International Economic Review, vol. 34, no. 4, pp. 873–901, 1993.
[4]  J. J. Laffont and J. Tirole, A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, USA, 1993.
[5]  J. D. Dana and K. E. Spier, “Designing a private industry. Government auctions with endogenous market structure,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 53, no. 1, pp. 127–147, 1994.
[6]  L. A. Stole, “Information expropriation and moral hazard in optimal second-source auctions,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 54, no. 3, pp. 463–484, 1994.
[7]  T. G. McGuire and M. H. Riordan, “Incomplete information and optimal market structure public purchases from private providers,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 56, no. 1, pp. 125–141, 1995.
[8]  M. Chalkley and J. M. Malcomson, “Contracting for health services with unmonitored quality,” Economic Journal, vol. 108, no. 449, pp. 1093–1110, 1998.
[9]  H. Gravelle, “Capitation contracts: access and quality,” Journal of Health Economics, vol. 18, no. 3, pp. 315–340, 1999.
[10]  M. Chalkley and J. H. Malcomson, “Government purchasing of health services,” in Handbook of Health Economics, A. J. Culyer and J. P. Newhouse, Eds., pp. 461–536, North-Holland, New York, NY, USA, 2000.
[11]  D. E. M. Sappington, “Regulating service quality: a survey,” Journal of Regulatory Economics, vol. 27, no. 2, pp. 123–154, 2005.
[12]  R. Levaggi, “Hospital health care: pricing and quality control in a spatial model with asymmetry of information,” International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, vol. 5, no. 4, pp. 327–349, 2005.
[13]  R. Levaggi, “Regulating internal markets for hospital care,” Journal of Regulatory Economics, vol. 32, no. 2, pp. 173–193, 2007.
[14]  M. Harrison, “Competition, regulation and private schools,” Australian Economic Review, vol. 38, no. 1, pp. 66–74, 2005.
[15]  G. de Fraja and P. Landeras, “Could do better: the effectiveness of incentives and competition in schools,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 90, no. 1-2, pp. 189–213, 2006.
[16]  R. Fischer, P. González, and P. Serra, “Does competition in privatized social services work? The Chilean experience,” World Development, vol. 34, no. 4, pp. 647–664, 2006.
[17]  G. T. Henry and C. S. Gordon, “Competition in the sondbox: a test of the effects of preschool competition on educational outcomes,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, vol. 25, no. 1, pp. 97–127, 2006.
[18]  D. P. Kessler and M. B. McClellan, “Is hospital competition socially wasteful?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 115, no. 2, pp. 577–615, 2000.
[19]  A. Enthoven, “Introducing market forces into health care: a tale of two countries,” in Proceedings of the 4th European Conference on Health Economics, Paris, France, July 2002, http://perso.wanadoo.fr/ces/Pages/english/PLS3.pdf.
[20]  M. S. Gaynor and W. B. Vogt, “Competition among hospitals,” RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 34, no. 4, pp. 764–785, 2003.
[21]  M. Duggan, “Does contracting out increase the efficiency of government programs? Evidence from medicaid HMOs,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 88, no. 12, pp. 2549–2572, 2004.
[22]  J. M. Abraham, M. Gaynor, and W. B. Vogt, “Entry and competition in local hospital markets,” The Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 55, no. 2, pp. 265–288, 2007.
[23]  A. Amirkhanyan, “Privatizing public nursing homes: examining the effects on quality and access,” Public Administration Review, vol. 68, no. 4, pp. 665–680, 2008.
[24]  R. P. Ellis, “Creaming, skimping and dumping: provider competition on the intensive and extensive margins,” Journal of Health Economics, vol. 17, no. 5, pp. 537–555, 1998.
[25]  J. Schnellenbach, “Nudges and norms: on the political economy of soft paternalism,” European Journal of Political Economy, vol. 28, no. 2, pp. 266–277, 2012.
[26]  P. Francois, “Public service motivation as an argument for government provision,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 78, no. 3, pp. 275–299, 2000.
[27]  P. Francois, “Employee care and the role of nonprofit organizations,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, vol. 157, no. 3, pp. 443–464, 2001.
[28]  A. Glazer, “Motivating devoted workers,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol. 22, no. 3, pp. 427–440, 2004.
[29]  R. Levaggi, M. Moretto, and V. Rebba, “Investment decisions in hospital technology when physicians are devoted workers,” Economics of Innovation and New Technology, vol. 18, no. 5, pp. 487–512, 2009.
[30]  S. G. Cheng, D. M. Reeves, Y. Vorobeychik, and M. P. Wellman, “Notes on equilibria in symmetric games,” in Proceedings of the International Joint Conference on Autonomous Agents & Multi Agent Systems, 6th Workshop On Game Theoretic and Decision Theoretic Agents, New Yorks, NY, USA, August 2004.
[31]  M. Harris and A. Raviv, “Optimal incentive contracts with imperfect information,” Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 20, no. 2, pp. 231–259, 1979.
[32]  M. Riordan and D. Sappington, “Awarding monopoly franchises,” American Economic Review, vol. 77, no. 3, pp. 375–387, 1987.
[33]  A. Wolinsky, “Regulation of duopoly: managed competition vs regulated monopolies,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, vol. 6, no. 4, pp. 821–847, 1997.
[34]  V. Krishna, Auction Theory, Academic Press, San Diego, Calif, USA, 2002.
[35]  M. Armstrong and D. E. M. Sappington, “Regulation, competition, and liberalization,” Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 44, no. 2, pp. 325–366, 2006.
[36]  A. Petretto, “Efficienza dei servizi pubblici locali ed efficienza del sistema economico: una nota propedeutica alla ricerca empirica,” SIEP WorkiNg Paper no. 592, 2007, http://www.unipv.it/websiep/wp/592.pdf.
[37]  E. G. Olds, “A note on the convolution of uniform distributions,” The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, vol. 23, no. 2, pp. 282–285, 1952.
[38]  D. M. Bradley and R. C. Gupta, “On the distribution of the sum of n non-identically distributed uniform random variables,” Annals of the Institute of Statistical Mathematics, vol. 54, no. 3, pp. 689–700, 2002.
[39]  L. Levaggi and R. Levaggi, “Dutch first price auctions for public service provision,” SSRN WorkiNg Paper no. 992660, 2009, http://ssrn.com/abstract=992660.
[40]  N. Malyshev, “Regulatory policy: OECD experience and evidence,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol. 22, no. 2, pp. 274–299, 2006.
[41]  D. B?s and G. de Fraja, “Quality and outside capacity in the provision of health services,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 84, no. 2, pp. 199–218, 2002.
[42]  L. Levaggi and R. Levaggi, “Strategic costs and preferences revelation in the allocation of resources for health care,” International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, vol. 10, no. 3, pp. 239–256, 2010.
[43]  G. Calzolari and G. Spagnolo, “Reputational commitments and collusion in procurement,” Mimeo, University of Bologna and Consip Research Unit, Stockholm School of Economics, 2006, http://www.dse.unibo.it/calzolari/web/papers/reputation.pdf.

Full-Text

Contact Us

service@oalib.com

QQ:3279437679

WhatsApp +8615387084133