[1] | Granovetter M ([1974] 1995) Getting a job: A study of contacts and careers. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
|
[2] | Granovetter MS (1973) The strength of weak ties. Am J Sociol 78: 1360–1380. doi: 10.1086/225469
|
[3] | Flap H, V?lker B (2001) Goal specific social capital and job satisfaction: Effects of different types of networks on instrumental and social aspects of work. Soc Networks 23: 297–320. doi: 10.1016/s0378-8733(01)00044-2
|
[4] | House JS, Landis KR, Umberson D (1988) Social relationships and health. Science 241: 540–545. doi: 10.1126/science.3399889
|
[5] | Krackhardt D (1987) Cognitive social structures. Soc Networks 9: 109–134. doi: 10.1016/0378-8733(87)90009-8
|
[6] | Burt RS (1995) Structural holes: The social structure of competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
|
[7] | Flap H (1999) Creation and returns of social capital. La Revue Tocqueville 20: 1–22.
|
[8] | Rusbult CE, Verette J, Whitney GA, Slovik LF, Lipkus I (1991) Accommodation processes in close relationships: Theory and preliminary empirical evidence. J Pers Soc Psychol 6: 53–78. doi: 10.1037//0022-3514.60.1.53
|
[9] | Rusbult CE, Martz JM (1995) Remaining in an abusive relationship: An investment model analysis of nonvoluntary dependence. Pers Soc Psychol Bull 21: 558–571. doi: 10.1177/0146167295216002
|
[10] | V?lker B, Flap H (1995) The effects of institutional transformation on personal networks. east germany, four years later. Neth J Soc Sci 31: 87–110.
|
[11] | V?lker B, Flap H (1997) The comrades' belief: Intended and unintended consequences of communism for neighbourhood relations in the former GDR. Eur Sociol Rev 13: 241–265. doi: 10.1093/oxfordjournals.esr.a018217
|
[12] | V?lker B, Flap H (1999) Getting ahead in the GDR social capital and status attainment under communism. Acta Sociol 42: 17–34. doi: 10.1177/000169939904200102
|
[13] | Scheepers P, Te Grotenhuis M, Gelissen J (2002) Welfare states and dimensions of social capital: Cross-national comparisons of social contacts in european countries. Eur Soc 4: 185–207. doi: 10.1080/14616690220142781
|
[14] | Bala V, Goyal S (2003) A noncooperative model of network formation. Econometrica 68: 1181–1229. doi: 10.1111/1468-0262.00155
|
[15] | Jackson MO, Wolinsky A (1996) A strategic model of social and economic networks. J Econ Theory 71: 44–74. doi: 10.1006/jeth.1996.0108
|
[16] | Suri S, Watts DJ (2011) Cooperation and contagion in web-based, networked public goods experiments. PLoS ONE 6: e16836. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0016836
|
[17] | Gruji? J, Fosco C, Araujo L, Cuesta JA, Sánchez A (2010) Social experiments in the mesoscale: Humans playing a spatial prisoner's dilemma. PLoS ONE 5: e13749. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0013749
|
[18] | Gracia-Lázaro C, Ferrer A, Ruiz G, Tarancón A, Cuesta JA, et al. (2012) Heterogeneous networks do not promote cooperation when humans play a Prisoner's dilemma. Proc Natl Acad Sci 109: 12922–12926. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1206681109
|
[19] | Cassar A (2007) Coordination and cooperation in local, random and small world networks: Experimental evidence. Games Econ Behav 58: 209–230. doi: 10.1016/j.geb.2006.03.008
|
[20] | Buskens V, van de Rijt A (2008) Dynamics of networks if everyone strives for structural holes. Am J Sociol 114: 371–407. doi: 10.1086/590674
|
[21] | Buskens V, Corten R, Weesie J (2008) Consent or conflict: Coevolution of coordination and networks. J Peace Res 45: 205–222. doi: 10.1177/0022343307087177
|
[22] | Corten R, Buskens V (2010) Co-evolution of conventions and networks: An experimental study. Soc Networks 32: 4–15. doi: 10.1016/j.socnet.2009.04.002
|
[23] | Perc M, Szolnoki A (2010) Coevolutionary games—A mini review. BioSystems 99: 109–125. doi: 10.1016/j.biosystems.2009.10.003
|
[24] | Rand DG, Arbesman S, Christakis NA (2011) Dynamic social networks promote cooperation in experiments with humans. Proc Natl Acad Sci 108: 19193–19198. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1108243108
|
[25] | Buskens V, Corten R, Raub W (2014) Social networks. forthcoming in: Braun N, saam NJ, editors. Handbuch modellbildung und simulation in den sozialwissenschaften. wiesbaden: VS-verlag für sozialwissenschaften/springer fachmedien. In Press.
|
[26] | Burger MJ, Buskens V (2009) Social context and network formation: An experimental study. Soc Networks 31: 63–75. doi: 10.1016/j.socnet.2008.10.001
|
[27] | Callander S, Plott CR (2005) Principles of network development and evolution: An experimental study. J Public Econ 89: 1469–1495. doi: 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.03.009
|
[28] | Falk A, Kosfeld M (2012) It's all about connections: Evidence on network formation. RNE 11: Article 2.
|
[29] | Goeree JK, Riedl A, Ule A (2009) In search of stars: Network formation among heterogeneous agents. Games Econ Behav 67: 445–466. doi: 10.1016/j.geb.2008.12.005
|
[30] | Berninghaus SK, Ehrhart KM, Ott M (2006) A network experiment in continuous time: The influence of link costs. Exp Econ 9: 237–251. doi: 10.1007/s10683-006-9125-1
|
[31] | Berninghaus SK, Ehrhart KM, Ott M, Vogt B (2007) Evolution of networks—an experimental analysis. J Evol Econ 17: 317–347. doi: 10.1007/s00191-006-0050-4
|
[32] | Coleman JS (1994) Foundations of social theory. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
|
[33] | Raub W, Buskens V, van Assen MALM (2011) Micro-macro links and microfoundations in sociology. J Math Sociol 35: 1–25. doi: 10.1080/0022250x.2010.532263
|
[34] | Lindenberg S (1992) The method of decreasing abstraction. In: Coleman JS, Fararo TJ, editors. Rational Choice Theory. Advocacy and Critique. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications. pp. 3–20.
|
[35] | Camerer CF (2003) Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
|
[36] | G?chter S, Herrmann B (2011) The limits of self-governance when cooperators get punished: Experimental evidence from urban and rural russia. Eur Econ Rev 55: 193–210. doi: 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2010.04.003
|
[37] | Gintis H, Fehr E (2007) Human nature and social cooperation. Annu Rev Sociol 33: 1–22. doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.33.040406.131812
|
[38] | Herings P, Mauleon A, Vannetelbosch V (2009) Farsightedly stable networks. Games Econ Behav 67: 526–541. doi: 10.1016/j.geb.2008.12.009
|
[39] | Page FH, Wooders MH, Kamat S (2005) Networks and farsighted stability. J Econ Theory 120: 257–269. doi: 10.1016/j.jet.2004.02.007
|
[40] | Morbitzer D, Buskens V, Rosenkranz S, Raub W (2013) How farsightedness Affects network formation. forthcoming in analyse und kritik. In Press.
|
[41] | Liebrand WBG (1984) The effect of social motives, communication and group size on behaviour in an N-person multi-stage mixed-motive game. Eur J Soc Psychol 14: 239–264. doi: 10.1002/ejsp.2420140302
|
[42] | Kelley HH, Thibaut JW (1978) Interpersonal relations: A theory of interdependence. New York: Wiley.
|
[43] | Liebrand WBG, McClintock CG (1988) The ring measure of social values: A computerized procedure for assessing individual differences in information processing and social value orientation. Eur J Pers 2: 217–230. doi: 10.1002/per.2410020304
|
[44] | Barr A, Zeitlin A (2010) Dictator games in the lab and in nature: External validity tested and investigated in ugandan primary schools. Centre for the Study of African Economies, University of Oxford.
|
[45] | Carpenter J, Myers CK (2010) Why volunteer? evidence on the role of altruism, image, and incentives. J Public Econ 94: 911–920. doi: 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2010.07.007
|
[46] | Van Lange PAM, Bekkers R, Schuyt TNM, Van Vugt M (2007) From games to giving: Social value orientation predicts donations to noble causes. Basic Appl Soc Psych 29: 375–384. doi: 10.1080/01973530701665223
|
[47] | Van Vugt M, Van Lange PAM, Meertens RM (1996) Commuting by car or public transportation? A social dilemma analysis of travel mode judgements. Eur J Soc Psychol 26: 373–395. doi: 10.1002/(sici)1099-0992(199605)26:3<373::aid-ejsp760>3.3.co;2-t
|
[48] | Adams JS (1963) Towards an understanding of inequity. J Abnorm Soc Psychol 67: 422–436. doi: 10.1037/h0040968
|
[49] | Bolton GE, Ockenfels A (2000) ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. Am Econ Rev 90: 166–193. doi: 10.1257/aer.90.1.166
|
[50] | Fehr E, Schmidt KM (1999) A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Q J Econ 114: 817–868. doi: 10.1162/003355399556151
|
[51] | Lurie S (1987) A parametric model of utility for two-person distributions. Psychol Rev 94: 42–60. doi: 10.1037/0033-295x.94.1.42
|
[52] | Van Lange PAM (1999) The pursuit of joint outcomes and equality in outcomes: An integrative model of social value orientation. J Pers Soc Psychol 77: 337–349. doi: 10.1037//0022-3514.77.2.337
|
[53] | Aksoy O, Weesie J (2012) Beliefs about the social orientations of others: A parametric test of the triangle, false consensus, and cone hypotheses. J Exp Soc Psychol 48: 45–54. doi: 10.1016/j.jesp.2011.07.009
|
[54] | Messick DM, Thorngate WB (1967) Relative gain maximization in experimental games. J Exp Soc Psychol 3: 85–101. doi: 10.1016/0022-1031(67)90039-x
|
[55] | Loewenstein GF, Thompson L, Bazerman MH (1989) Social utility and decision making in interpersonal contexts. J Pers Soc Psychol 57: 426–441. doi: 10.1037//0022-3514.57.3.426
|
[56] | Dawes CT, Fowler JH, Johnson T, McElreath R, Smirnov O (2007) Egalitarian motives in humans. Nature 446: 794–796. doi: 10.1038/nature05651
|
[57] | Van Lange PAM, Kuhlman DM (1994) Social value orientations and impressions of partner's honesty and intelligence: A test of the might versus morality effect. J Pers Soc Psychol 67: 126. doi: 10.1037//0022-3514.67.1.126
|
[58] | Camerer CF, Fehr E (2006) When does “economic man” dominate social behavior? Science 311: 47–52. doi: 10.1126/science.1110600
|
[59] | Greiner B (2004) The online recruitment system ORSEE 2.0 - A guide for the organization of experiments in economics. University of Cologne, Working Paper Series in Economics 10.
|
[60] | Central Committee on Research involving Human Subjects (2002) Manual for the review of medical research involving human subjects. Available: www.ccmo-online.nl.
|
[61] | Fischbacher U (2007) z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp Econ 10: 171–178. doi: 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4
|
[62] | Griesinger DW, Livingston JW Jr (1973) Toward a model of interpersonal motivation in experimental games. Behav Sci 18: 173–188. doi: 10.1002/bs.3830180305
|
[63] | McFadden D (1973) Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior. In: Zarembka P, editor. New York, NY: Academic press. pp. 105–142.
|
[64] | Mosteller F (1951) Remarks on the method of paired comparisons: II. the effect of an aberrant standard deviation when equal standard deviations and equal correlations are assumed. Psychometrika 16: 203–206. doi: 10.1007/bf02289115
|
[65] | Mosteller F (1951) Remarks on the method of paired comparisons: I. the least squares solution assuming equal standard deviations and equal correlations. Psychometrika 16: 3–9. doi: 10.1007/bf02313422
|
[66] | Mosteller F (1951) Remarks on the method of paired comparisons: III. A test of significance for paired comparisons when equal standard deviations and equal correlations are assumed. Psychometrika 16: 207–218. doi: 10.1007/bf02289116
|
[67] | Thurstone LL (1927) The method of paired comparisons for social values. J Abnorm Soc Psychol 21: 384–400. doi: 10.1037/h0065439
|
[68] | Thurstone LL (1927) Psychophysical analysis. Am J Psychol 38: 368–389. doi: 10.2307/1415006
|
[69] | Maddala GS (1986) Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press.
|
[70] | Snijders TAB, Bosker RJ (1999) Multilevel analysis: An introduction to basic and advanced multilevel modeling. London UK: Sage Publications Limited.
|
[71] | Binmore K (1998) Game theory and the social contract-vol. 2: Just playing. Cambridge, MA: MIT press.
|
[72] | Kreps DM (1990) Game theory and economic modelling. Oxford UK: Oxford University Press.
|
[73] | Charness G (2000) Responsibility and effort in an experimental labor market. J Econ Behav Organ 42: 375–384. doi: 10.1016/s0167-2681(00)00096-2
|
[74] | Rand DG, Greene JD, Nowak MA (2012) Spontaneous giving and calculated greed. Nature 489: 427–430. doi: 10.1038/nature11467
|